- Acumen Powered by Robins Kaplan LLP®
- Affirmative Recovery
- American Indian Law and Policy
- Antitrust and Trade Regulation
- Appellate Advocacy and Guidance
- Business Litigation
- Civil Rights and Police Misconduct
- Class Action Litigation
- Commercial/Project Finance and Real Estate
- Corporate Governance and Special Situations
- Corporate Restructuring and Bankruptcy
- Domestic and International Arbitration
- Entertainment and Media Litigation
- Health Care Litigation
- Insurance and Catastrophic Loss
- Intellectual Property and Technology Litigation
- Mass Tort Attorneys
- Medical Malpractice Attorneys
- Personal Injury Attorneys
- Telecommunications Litigation and Arbitration
- Wealth Planning, Administration, and Fiduciary Disputes
Acumen Powered by Robins Kaplan LLP®
Ediscovery, Applied Science and Economics, and Litigation Support Solutions
-
November 1, 2024Robins Kaplan Recognized for “Tipping the Scales” by Diversity & Flexibility Alliance
-
October 28, 2024Philip Sieff Honored with Minnesota Icon Award
-
October 24, 2024Mid-Minnesota Legal Aid, Robins Kaplan Bring Class Action Suit Against Mobile Home Park
-
November 7, 2024Building Your Legal Brand in a Digital World
-
November 7, 2024Financial Literacy for Associates
-
November 7, 2024Structuring IP Finance Deals That Work
-
September 2024Meet Our New Partner and Trial Advocacy Seminar Keynote Speaker: B. Todd Jones
-
September 18, 2024Astellas Pharma, Inc. v. Sandoz Inc.
-
September 2024Q&A with Alan Harter, Founder of Pactolus Private Wealth Management
-
September 16, 2022Uber Company Systems Compromised by Widespread Cyber Hack
-
September 15, 2022US Averts Rail Workers Strike With Last-Minute Tentative Deal
-
September 14, 2022Hotter-Than-Expected August Inflation Prompts Massive Wall Street Selloff
Find additional firm contact information for press inquiries.
Find resources to help navigate legal and business complexities.
A Lawful Monopoly? The Intersection Between Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law
April 23, 1999
Over the past five years, much has been written and discussed about the importance of a business incorporating its intellectual property portfolio into its strategic marketing plan. While the owner of patent rights holds many natural advantages in today's commercial and legal landscape, that patent holder must be sensitive to the limits that antitrust law places upon the wielding of those rights in the marketplace.
There was a time when the only type of acceptable monopoly were the hotels that you could place on Boardwalk and Park Place in the Parker Brothers board game. As many commentators have noted, however, especially with the maturation of the Federal Circuit, the legal community has embraced a policy of encouraging innovation by way of the statutory patent monopoly over a policy of promoting competition by way of antitrust and trade regulation laws. As with all paradigmatic shifts in the law, this leaves those caught on the outside -- in this case the putative infringers -- searching for new or creative ways to breathe life into older doctrines and shift the balance of power back in their favor. As a result, it is likely that holders of patent rights will increasingly face challenges that the patent holder has acted in an anti-competitive fashion.
The Historic Tension Between Patent And Antitrust Law
As the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals has recently noted, "At the border of intellectual property monopolies and antitrust markets lies a field of dissonance yet to be harmonized by statute or by the Supreme Court. Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997) ("Kodak II"). This "dissonance" is largely due to the fact that tension has historically existed between antitrust law and intellectual property law. The tension between these two areas of the law is perhaps best summarized by the Second Circuit in SCM Corp. v. Xerox Corp. 645 F.2d 1195, 1203-05 (2d Cir. 1981):
The conflict between the antitrust and patent laws arises in the methods they embrace that were designed to achieve reciprocal goals. While the antitrust laws proscribe unreasonable restraints of competition, the patent laws reward the inventor with a temporary monopoly that insulates him from competitive exploitation of his patented art. . . .
When the patented product is so successful that it evolves into its own economic market . . . or succeeds in engulfing a large section of a preexisting product market, the patent and antitrust laws necessarily clash. In such cases the primary purpose of the antitrust laws -- to preserve competition -- can be frustrated, albeit temporarily, by a holder's exercise of the patent's inherent exclusionary power during its term.
At the heart of this tension is the fact that antitrust law is premised upon economics, while patent law is based upon technology. These two disciplines are themselves separate and distinct, drawing upon different analytic frameworks. Accordingly, judges, faced with the difficult task of determining which substantive area of the law should be entitled to primacy, reach inconsistent and ad hoc decisions from which few general rules can be drawn.
The Spectrum Of Permissible Conduct
As with most legal issues, merely placing bounds upon inquiry provides at least a useful starting point for the analysis. Fortunately, two more or less clear principles have emerged regarding the interplay between these areas of the law.
- First, as a general rule, patent holders may unilaterally refuse to license their patent technology to third parties without fear of violating the antitrust laws. Data General Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147, 1187 (1st Cir. 1994); 35 U.S.C. § 271(d).
- Second, it is clear that, notwithstanding protections afforded under § 271(d), a patent holder will not be immune from the antitrust laws if it seeks to extend its patent monopoly beyond its "natural scope":
The Court has held many times that power gained through some natural and legal advantage such as a patent, copyright, or business acumen can give rise to liability if a seller exploits his dominant position in one market to expand his empire into the next.
Kodak I, 504 U.S. at 480, n. 29.
Obviously, there is an almost infinite range of possible conduct lying along the spectrum that exists between these two extremes. Resolution as to the legality of any particular practice will depend largely upon how successfully the litigants can portray it as one extreme or the other. The following examples illustrate the various practices involving patent rights that have been challenged as implicating the antitrust laws:
- Tying arrangements - where the patentee is willing to sell or license a patented product only on the condition that the purchaser/licensee also purchase, or agree not to purchase, another article of commerce - are not within the scope of the patent monopoly. E.g., Senza Gel Corp. v. Seiffhart, 803 F. 2d 661. 664-5 (Fed. Cir. 1986).
- Post-expiration royalties or restraints (e.g., regulations contractually requiring a licensee to continue to pay royalties, or limit its use of the patented technology, after the patent expires) are illegal. Brulotte v. Thys Co. 379 U.S. 29 (1964).
- Resale price restrictions on the patented article are improper. Ethyl Gasoline Corp. v. U.S., 309 U.S. 436 (1940).
- Agreements among competitors or licensees setting the price of patented articles, or agreements not to license third parties, can be treated as illegal conspiracies. See Mannington Mills, Inc. v. Congoleum Industries, Inc., 610 F.2d 1059, 1073 (3rd Cir. 1979).
- Generally, field of use and territorial limitations are acceptable. Continental T.V. Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977); Mallinckrodt, Inc. v. Medipart, Inc. 976 F.2d 700 (Fed. Cir. 1992) (upholding single use restrictions).
- Finally, while there is a presumption that a patentee may unilaterally refuse to license its patent, that presumption may be rebutted if the patentee engages in a scheme to foreclose competition or has no "legitimate competitive reasons for the refusal." Kodak I, 504 U.S. 451, 483 n.32 (1992); see also, Kodak II (holding that Kodak's refusal to sell replacement parts to Independent Service Organizations on the grounds that some of the parts were patented was pretextual and thus violated the antitrust laws).
The Future?
In Kodak I, the Supreme Court explicitly recognized that, in appropriate circumstances, it was acceptable to define a relevant market in terms of a single brand of product, if there was evidence that customers had been "locked into" continued use of or reliance upon that brand because of technological or informational barriers. Although it is now commonplace to state that market power does not flow automatically from intellectual property,(1) Kodak's recognition of single brand relevant markets renders it much easier to define the relevant market as consisting solely of a patented item. Variations on this "lock in" theory have already been used by the government in its cases against both Intel and Microsoft. The FTC is accusing Intel of refusing to sell patented chip technology to companies who rely on that technology to build Intel based systems, unless the companies agree to license some of their own technology back to Intel. The case is set to begin on March 9. In the Microsoft case, the government is employing a tying theory, among others, to argue that Microsoft is abusing the economic power associated with its patents and copyrights in operating systems now that industries and the public have standardized on those systems. This case is entering its final stages.
Ultimately, if an antitrust plaintiff succeeds in defining the relevant market consonant with patented technology, the patent holder may face serious consequences. See Grid Systems Grp. v. Texas Instruments, 771 F. Supp. 1033, 1037 (N.D. Cal. 1991) (presumption of market power arising from patent rights survived the "safe harbor" amendments to § 271(d)). Although for the moment, the trend definitely appears to be in favor of defining the scope of a patent monopoly broadly, thereby preempting any claims that the patentee is unfairly wielding market power in a relevant market, a clear doctrinal basis exists for reversing that trend should litigants and courts wish to seize upon it.
E.g., 35 U.S.C. § 271(d) (patentee cannot be guilty of misuse without proof of market power); Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (intellectual property, by itself, does not create market power).
© Copyright 1999. All Rights Reserved.The articles on our website include some of the publications and papers authored by our attorneys, both before and after they joined our firm. The content of these articles should not be taken as legal advice. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or official position of Robins Kaplan LLP.
Related Professionals
Related Publications
Related News
If you are interested in having us represent you, you should call us so we can determine whether the matter is one for which we are willing or able to accept professional responsibility. We will not make this determination by e-mail communication. The telephone numbers and addresses for our offices are listed on this page. We reserve the right to decline any representation. We may be required to decline representation if it would create a conflict of interest with our other clients.
By accepting these terms, you are confirming that you have read and understood this important notice.